SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
 issue99Friedrich von Wieser, pioneer in the study of society within Austrian thoughtCommunity Water Management in the ColombianPost-Conflict author indexsubject indexarticles search
Home Pagealphabetic serial listing  

Services on Demand

Journal

Article

Indicators

Related links

  • On index processCited by Google
  • Have no similar articlesSimilars in SciELO
  • On index processSimilars in Google

Share


Lecturas de Economía

Print version ISSN 0120-2596

Lect. Econ.  no.99 Medellín July/Dec. 2023  Epub July 08, 2024

https://doi.org/10.17533/udea.le.n99a352279 

Artículos

Real Equilibrium Exchange Rate in Colombia: Thousands of VEC Models Approach

Tipo de cambio de equilibrio real en Colombia: aproximación mediante miles de modelos VEC

Taux de change d’équilibre réel en Colombie: approximation à l’aide de miles de modèles VEC

Andrea Salazar-Díaza 

Aarón Levi Garavito-Acostab 

Sergio Restrepo-Ángelc 

Leidy Viviana Arcila-Agudelod 

a Andrea Salazar-Díaz: Analyst from Banco de la República, Inflation and Macroeconomic Programming Department, Bogotá, Colombia. E-mail: asalazdi@banrep.gov.co https://orcid.org/0000-0001-7897-1171

b Aarón Levi Garavito-Acosta: Head of the Macroeconomic Programming Section from Banco de la República, Inflation and Macroeconomic Programming Department, Bogotá, Colombia. E-mail: agaravac@banrep.gov.co https://orcid.org/0000-0002-0592-2966

c Sergio Restrepo-Ángel : Senior Analyst from Banco de la República, Inflation and Macroeconomic Programming Department, Bogotá, Colombia. E-mail: srestran@banrep.gov.co https://orcid.org/0000-0002-9811-3673

d Leidy Viviana Arcila-Agudelo: Intern from Banco de la República, Inflation and Macroeconomic Programming Department, Bogotá, Colombia. E-mail: viviargu3@gmail.com https://orcid.org/0000-0003-2706-4381


Resumen

La metodología Behavioral Equilibrium Exchange Rate (BEER) sugiere muchas variables como fundamentales de la tasa de cambio real de equilibrio (TCRE). Esto genera incertidumbre en la especificación de los modelos debido a que la TCRE depende y varía, a menudo de manera drástica, del conjunto particular de variables elegidas. Abordamos este problema estimando miles de especifica- ciones de vectores de corrección de errores (VEC) para datos colombianos entre el primer trimestre de 2000 y el cuarto trimestre de 2019. De acuerdo con una extensa revisión de la literatura, empleamos treinta y cinco proxies clasificadas entre cinco grupos fijos de fundamentales económicos que subyacen la TCRE: endeudamiento, sector fiscal, productividad, términos de intercambio y diferenciales de tasas de interés. Nuestro enfoque deriva una distribución empírica de la TCRE que nos permite afirmar con mayor certeza, entre cientos de especificaciones económicas plausibles, si el tipo de cambio real está desalineado o en equilibrio.

Palabras clave: VEC; BEER; tipo de cambio real; productividad; términos de intercambio.

Abstract

Behavioral Equilibrium Exchange Rate (BEER) models propose a wide range of variables as potential drivers of equilibrium real exchange rates (ERER). This gives rise to model uncertainty issues due to the often drastic dependence and variability of ERER on a particular set of chosen variables. We address this issue by estimating thousands of Vector Error Correction (VEC) specifications using Colombian data spanning from the first quarter of 2000 to the fourth quarter of 2019. Based on an extensive literature review, we employ thirty-five proxies categorized among five fixed groups of economic fundamentals that underlie the ERER: Indebtedness, Fiscal sector, Productivity, Terms-of-Trade, and Interest Rate Differentials. Our approach derives an empirical distribution of ERER that allows us to determine with greater certainty, among hundreds of plausible economic specifications, whether the real exchange rate is misaligned or in equilibrium.

JEL Classification:

F31, F32, F41, C32.

Keywords: Real exchange rate; VEC; BEER; Productivity; Terms-of-Trade

Résumé

Les modèles comportementaux de taux de change d’équilibre (BEER) suggèrent de nom- breuses variables comme moteurs possibles des taux de change réels d’équilibre (ERER). Cela donne lieu à des problèmes d’incertitude du modèle, car le TREER dépend et varie, souvent de manière drastique, d’un ensemble particulier de variables choisies. Nous avons résolu ce problème en estimant des milliers de spécifications de correction d’erreurs vectorielles (VEC) pour les données colombiennes entre le premier trimestre 2000 et le quatrième trimestre 2019. Sur la base d’un examen approfondi de la lit- térature, nous avons utilisé trente-cinq proxys classés parmi cinq groupes de fondamentaux économiques fixés sous-jacents aux ERER: endettement, secteur budgétaire, productivité, termes de l’échange et dif- férentiels de taux d’intérêt. Notre approche dérive une distribution ERER empirique qui nous permet d’établir avec plus de certitude, parmi des centaines de spécifications économiques plausibles, si le taux de change réel est désaligné ou en équilibre.

Mots clés: VEC; BEER; taux de change réel; productivité; termes de l’échange.

Introduction

The real exchange rate (RER) and its misalignment from its long-term equilibrium are key inputs for assessing a country’s macroeconomic imbalance. The equilibrium real exchange rate (ERER) helps policymakers to deter- mine whether nominal exchange rate movements obey to temporary shocks that are likely to dissipate in the short term or are determined by more permanent changes in fundamental macroeconomic variables (Clark & MacDonald, 1998). In this sense, economic theory has approached the estimation of an RER long-term (or equilibrium) path through multiple methodologies. Given the multiple notions of equilibrium, a problem that arises is that the ERER estimates span over too many mixed results. Additionally, the results will still depend on several modeling assumptions, even when considering only a particular methodology (Adler & Grisse, 2017).

The literature has developed different methodologies to define and approach the ERER notion (Clark & MacDonald 1998; De Grauwe & Mongelli, 2005; Edwards, 1989; Isard, 2007; Obstfeld & Rogoff, 1996; Sarno & Taylor, 2003, among many others). The first, and one of the most commonly used, is the purchasing power parity (PPP), which is a generalization of the law of one price. A second one is the Fundamental Equilibrium Exchange Rate (FEER), which refers to the concept of medium-term equilibrium (Saxegaard et al., 2007; Rubaszek & Rawdanowicz, 2009). According to Fidora et al. (2021), it is obtained from the required adjustment of the exchange rate to equalize the medium-term sustainable value of the current account with its cyclically adjusted value. Stein (1990) proposed a third methodology named the natural real exchange rate (NATREX) approach, which defines the “natural” RER as “the RER that ensures the equilibrium of the balance of payments in the absence of cyclical factors, speculative capital movements and changes in international reserves”. The NATREX ensures internal and external equilibriums in the long run, specifically, when a country’s GDP converges to its potential level (or zero output gap), and the country’s current account attains a sustainable level. The fourth methodology is called Behavioral Equilibrium Exchange Rate (BEER), which uses cointegrated econometric methods to estimate an ERER that is determined by the long-term dynamics of the RER and its fundamentals.

This paper focuses on the BEER approach, as it is a methodology that uses economic fundamentals to explain the underlying structural movements of the ERER and derives a real exchange rate gap (or misalignment). This methodology is additionally utilized as an IMF’s tool for exchange rate assessments.1 According to Adler and Grisse (2017), a fundamental weakness of BEER models lies in the fact that structural macroeconomic models often incorporate multiple variables as potential explanatory variables for real exchange rates. Due to data limitations, it is often impossible (or impractical) to include all of these variables in the regression. The issue of model uncertainty arises due to the direct dependence of equilibrium rates and estimated coefficients on the particular model being estimated by the researcher. To ad- dress this, we establish five groups of multiple fundamentals that, according to the literature, best explain ERER movements: Indebtedness, Fiscal aggregates, Productivity, Terms-of-Trade (TOT) and Interest Rate Differentials. For each of the groups, we use several proxies.2 We estimated real exchange rate vector error correction (VEC) models3for all possible combinations of the fundamental variables across groups (always keeping one variable for each group of fundamentals). Thus, conducting iterations over the different variable specifications among each group results in 18,144 models (for further details, see Section III). It must be noted we are addressing only one specific and narrow type of model uncertainty, specifically the combinations of con- temporaneous variables of each type. From these models, we filter out those that exhibit coefficients with the expected sign and significance, as well as those whose residuals satisfy the non-autocorrelation, homoscedasticity, normality, and stationarity assumptions. We construct an empirical distribution for the RER equilibrium and its misalignment from the selected models.

It is important to note that the results can vary at some points in time due to fluctuations, sometimes significant, in the ERER of alternative specifications. Furthermore, because the long-term level of the RER (equilibrium) is an unobserved variable, selecting the most appropriate model is challenging since there is no reference that permits to evaluate the magnitude of the estimate’s error. Therefore, this paper explores the robustness of Colombia’s equilibrium real exchange rate using the BEER approach.

The document is organized as follows. The following section discusses the related literature and our contributions. The third section describes the study data and explains all the proxies used as fundamentals. The fourth section presents and derives the empirical strategy. The results are presented and discussed in the fifth section, and the conclusion and main findings are covered in the last section.

Literature Review

This section presents a literature review of papers that are closely related to the subject matter of this research. These papers have been selected because they offer estimates of ERER through a cointegration approach. A more detailed overview of variables that represents a relevant channel in the real exchange rate literature is provided in Table A1 of the appendix. The approach carried out in this document is framed within the BEER, as defined by Clark and MacDonald (1998). Under this methodology, the ERER is constructed based on reduced-form models and time series estimates that seek to capture how different variables determine the dynamics of the RER. In this sense, these models not only seek to explain the medium- and long-term dynamics of the exchange rate but also its short-term dynamics. According to this notion of equilibrium, the ERER varies over time and is specified as a function of its fundamentals, determined by macroeconomic theory. Using a VEC model, the authors distinguish between permanent (terms of trade, relative prices on non-traded to traded goods, the stock of net foreign assets, and a proxy for the risk premium) and transitory (interest rate differential) com- ponents of RER fundamentals for the G-3 currencies. They found that the BEER model was consistent with the theory as it explained actual movements of the real effective exchange rate.

Maeso-Fernández et al. (2002) present an empirical analysis of the medium- term determinants of the euro exchange rate. The empirical analysis derives a BEER and a Permanent Equilibrium Exchange Rate (PEER).4 Both models were rather similar, with the PEERs being smoother than the BEERs. Their study findings show that the variables of productivity, differentials in real interest rates, relative fiscal stance, and the real oil price have a significant influence on the euro’s effective exchange rate. Ricci and MacDonald (2003) estimate a VEC model to find the ERER in South Africa using quarterly data for the period 1970Q1 to 2002Q1. These authors consider the real interest rate differential, relative GDP per capita, real commodity prices, an openness indica- tor, the fiscal balance, and the net foreign assets (NFA) as determinants of the real exchange rate. Clark and MacDonald (2004) extend the BEER approach by using real interest rate differential, net foreign assets, and the relative price of non-traded/traded goods as economic fundamentals. Johansen cointegration methods are employed to decompose the fundamentals into transitory and permanent components. The permanent component was used to estimate the PEER for the pound sterling, U.S. dollar and Canadian dollar. For the U.S. dollar and the Canadian dollars, they found that the BEER and the PEER are remarkably similar and generally follow the observed exchange rate.

Paiva (2006) estimates the BEER model for Brazil through a VEC specification for the period 1970 to 2004. The author considers the relative price of non-tradable to tradable, terms of trade, real interest rate differentials, the net foreign assets position, and the relative stock of public domestic debt as the fundamentals related to the real exchange rate. After estimating the unit root test, the author determined that the real interest rate differential is stationary. These findings indicate that the absolute value of the interest rate differential coefficient in the cointegrating equation is relatively small, suggesting a minimal contribution.

Lee et al. (2008) describes all the methods used by the International Monetary Fund to evaluate the misalignment of the exchange rate in member countries. These authors classify the use of cointegration methods between the RER and its fundamentals within the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate methodology and describe an estimate of a panel VEC for 48 countries with annual data for the period 1980-2004. Caputo and Núñez (2008) estimate an equation for Chile’s RER based on its fundamental determinants using quarterly data for the period 1977-2007. These authors use the ratio between tradable and non-tradable productivity, Government spending, ToT, NFA, and tariff levels as fundamentals.

Bénassy-Quéré et al. (2009a) study the robustness of the equilibrium exchange rate estimations from BEER methods. They investigate industrial an emerging countries’ potential fundamentals that include net foreign asset position, relative productivity, interest-rate differential, and terms of trade. From this analysis, they conclude that BEER estimations are robust to several tests and that the productivity proxy tends to be the more sensible option.

Bussiére et al. (2010) carry out an analysis of the main methodologies for estimating the RER equilibrium, with a focus on describing the most recent methodological advances that allow an improvement in the estimation. For the estimation of a reduced form of the RER and its determinants, these authors recommend taking into account fundamentals related to trade restrictions, productivity, government consumption, capital formation, NFA, and commodity prices. For each combination of fundamentals, they select only those models that satisfy the criteria for the existence of a long-run relation- ship, those with significant level elasticities, and those whose coefficient meets the expected sign in line with the theoretical restrictions.

Adler and Grisse (2017) explore the robustness of BEER models addressing the issue of model uncertainty, which aligns with our research. They inves tigate this robustness by including country fixed effects and evaluate the sensitivity of the estimated coefficients to different combinations of economic fundamentals underlying the RER. In their estimation, the authors consider several variables such as trade balance, terms of trade, real interest rate, productivity, private credit, population growth, output gap, trade openness, old age dependency rate, net foreign assets, government consumption, GDP per capita, fiscal balance, fertility rate, and central bank reserves. They estimate thousands of RER regressions over all possible combinations of the aforementioned fundamentals, ranging from models with one or two variables to the inclusion of all variables. Finally, they construct the distribution of the misalignment across all cointegrating models to identify the median of the estimation. Their main finding is that the estimated coefficients and, consequently, the implied equilibrium exchange rates, are sensitive to several modeling assumptions. Therefore, it is important to exercise caution when interpreting the point estimates of equilibrium exchange rates and to explore how the effects of specific variables depend on the model’s specification. The reasons addressed by Adler and Grisse (2017) were the main motivation for our methodological approach.

Several papers have attempted to estimate ERER and RER misalignments for Colombia. Oliveros and Huertas-Campos (2003) were among the first to perform a VEC estimation to find the equilibrium RER with annual data during the period 1958-2001. The determinants used as a proxy for the Balassa- Samuelson effect were NFA, interest rate differential, and the relationship be- tween tradable and non-tradable prices. Echavarría et al. (2005) estimated a VEC with annual data for the period 1962-2004 and considered the following long-term determinants (fundamentals) of the RER: NFA, GDP growth differential between Colombia and the US, ToT, Government consumption, US RER and Colombia’s nominal COP/USD exchange rate. Later, Echavarría et al. (2007) estimated a common trend approach associated with a Structural VEC model to obtain an ERER for Colombia. In this case, they used annual data for the period 1962-2005 and the following fundamentals for the RER: NFA, ToT, and an openness indicator.

Alonso et al. (2008) proposed easy-to-follow alternative measures to periodically assess the evolution of the RER. A preliminary analysis was conducted to determine the degree to which its various methodologies were misaligned with respect to their long-term level. Puyana-Martínez (2010) estimated the relationship between relative tradable and non-tradable productivities using data from the Colombian manufacturing sector. The author identifies a strong correlation between this indicator and the RER for the period 1992-2004. Arteaga et al. (2013) studied the behavior of the RER between 1994 and 2012 using a cointegration model. Their results highlight the importance of national terms of trade and the Balassa-Samuelson effect in explaining the real appreciation observed since the end of 2003. Our work adds to this strand of literature by studying the dynamics of the real exchange rate in Colombia over a more recent period (2000-2019) and its robustness when changing variable specifications.

Data

We use quarterly data from the first quarter of 2000 to the fourth quarter of 2019. The selection of the period is constrained by the availability of information and the fact that Colombia has adopted a flexible exchange rate within the frame of an inflation-targeting regime. The variables in the dataset were seasonally adjusted using the Census X-13 method (if seasonality is present). All variables that were not percentages were introduced in their logarithmic transformation so that their magnitudes were comparable.

As previously stated, we classify all our variable specifications into five different groups (Table 1) and subsequently estimate the VEC models by iterating over the variables within each group. Each group represents a theoretically intuitive and relevant channel in the literature (Table A1 of the appendix). Given that each type corresponds to one of the relevant channels in the RER literature, we consider it appropriate to include one variable from each group in our candidate specifications. The variable in the first group is the logarithm of the real exchange rate index (RERI) that uses total weights5and the CPI as the deflator for all countries (section A of the appendix provides details on its construction). It is assumed to be the most endogenous because it responds to all the fundamentals. All the variables used, their detailed description and their source can be found in Table A3 of the appendix.

Fundamental determinants of ERER

This section will provide a comprehensive description of the groups of fundamental drivers, along with their constituent variables., The classification of the five fundamental variables that are widely recognized in the literature as the main drivers of the RER is presented in Table A1 of the appendix.

Fiscal. The relationship between the real exchange rate and fiscal policy has been analyzed from multiple perspectives in the literature. In the first place, Keynesian theories framed in the Mundell-Fleming model imply that a positive fiscal shock increases domestic demand. Along with sticky wages and prices, this induces a real appreciation (Mundell, 1963; Fleming, 1962; Badia & Segura- Ubiergo, 2014). In the case of real business cycle models, government spending shocks crowd out domestic private consumption, increasing labor supply and appreciating the real exchange rate (Backus et al., 1995). However, other studies, such as Ravn et al. (2007) and Kollmann (2010), find opposite results. Maeso- Fernández et al. (2006) and Badia and Segura-Ubiergo (2014) also highlight the role of the composition of government spending. In particular, the latter authors note that increases in government spending on non-tradable goods, financed either by taxes or debt, will generate a real appreciation. On the other hand, the effect of raises in public investment is unclear. As Balassa (1964) and Samuelson (1964) pointed out, an increase in public investment may appreciate the RER if there are gains in productivity in the tradable sector, but it may depreciate the RER if there are disproportionate increases in productivity in the non-tradable sector. Moreover, if both tradable and non-tradable sectors experience similar gains in productivity, the RER will not be affected (Galstyan & Lane, 2009).

In this work, we follow the New-Keynesian approach, according to which an increase in public spending generates an appreciation of the real exchange rate (negative sign), as it is more frequently channeled towards non-tradable goods and services (De Gregorio & Wolf, 1994; De Gregorio et al., 1994; Froot & Rogoff, 1995). The channel can be described as follows: as the GDP and aggregate demand increase, there is a subsequent rise in the demand for labor and capital, leading to higher wages and marginal costs and, consequently, inflation, which implies an increase in the policy rate and capital inflows, and an appreciation of the exchange rate.

Productivity. The inclusion of a productivity variable is commonly motivated by the Balassa- Samuelson theory, according to which the bigger the productivity gap in traded goods production between two countries, the larger the wage and price of services differences and, “correspondingly, the greater the gap between purchasing-power parity and the equilibrium exchange rate.” (Balassa, 1964, p 586). Because total factor productivity is difficult to measure, De Broeck and Slok (2006) and Fischer (2004) employ labor productivity me sures in different sectors and find evidence that a rise in productivity implies a real appreciation of the respective currency. As most of our variables are defined as ratios with Colombia in the denominator, the expected sign for the coefficients in this set of variables is positive.

Table 1 Fundamental Group Variables 

Public consumption % GDP quarters) Trade partners/COL index ratio
NFPS Spending % GDP Per capita trade partners/COL index ratio Per capita relative index USA/Col GDP PPP Per capita ratio USA/Col
Indebtedness Terms of Trade Int. Rate Diff
Public external debt outstanding Terms of Trade CE Dif Assets-Prime
Total external debt Terms of Trade PPI Diff FTD 90 days
NFA prime Real GDP Mining Terms of Trade Diff FTD 360-Prime
NFA GDP Implicit Real Oil Price Diff FTD-Prime
Real NFA Real Brent price Diff FTD-3mlibor
NFA prime GDP Private external debt NFA prime Real CNG Outstanding Debt National accounts Terms of Trade

Note: RERI: Real Exchange Rate Index; CNG: Central National Government; NFPS: Non-Financial Public Sector; T: Tradable; NT: Non- Tradable; PPP: Purchasing Power Parity; NFA: Net Foreign Assets; Prime: Prime rate; CE: Foreign Trade; PPI: Producer Price Index; FTD: Fixed-term Deposits; FTD360: Fixed-term Deposits 360 days’ rate; FTD3mlibor: Fixed-term Deposits 3-month LIBOR rate; GDP: Gross Domestic Product. See Table A3 of the appendix for a detailed description on each variable.

Source: Own elaboration.

Indebtedness. In this group, we include nine variables that offer different measures of indebtedness of the Colombian economy. This includes out- standing debt variables and Net Foreign Assets (NFA). In the case of the debt variables, the expected sign would be positive, as a more indebted country is perceived as riskier (Cosset & Roy, 1991). As emphasized by Ajevskis et al. (2014), “If a country is in a debtor’s position, net interest payments weigh on the current account balances. The latter requires strengthening international price competitiveness and a more depreciated real exchange rate.” (p. 104). Similarly, as Phillips et al. (2013) and Mano (2019) point out, NFA are expected to have a negative coefficient as a country with higher foreign borrowing (worse NFA position) requires a more depreciated RER to reduce its trade balance deficit.

Terms of Trade. Terms of trade proxy indicators should have negative signs. Neary (1988) indicates that more favorable terms of trade are associated with higher wealth and, thus, a more appreciated RER. According to Ajevskis et al. (2014), higher commodity terms of trade should lead to real exchange rate appreciation via real income effect. Calderón (2004) elaborates on this idea by stating that terms of trade improvements would increase tradable goods’ consumption and generate positive wealth effects that would reduce the sup- ply of labor in the non-tradable sector. This leads to a relative non-tradable goods price increase, thereby appreciating the RER.

Interest Rate Differentials. According to Adler and Grisse (2017) and Paiva (2006), real interest rate differentials should have a negative sign, which indicates that an increase in the differential will cause an appreciation of the RER. This is because a higher domestic interest rate relative to foreign interest rates offers investors higher returns in the country, thereby attracting foreign capital and, thus, an appreciated RER.

Empirical Strategy

We estimate thousands of Vector Error Correction (VEC) specifications for 2000Q1-2019Q4. Each model corresponds to a realization of all possible contemporaneous combinations of the fundamental variables across the groups described in part A of Section II (fixing one variable for each group

of fundamentals) for the RER specification. The latter is built as the multi- lateral RER index weighted by total non-traditional goods trade, deflated by the consumer price index (see section A of the appendix for further details). The estimated VEC corresponds to DRIFT models according to the usual notation (Arteaga et al., 2013; Johansen, 1992; Maeso-Fernández et al., 2006) with one lag and one cointegration relationship. 6

For this work, a maximum of lags p = 2 was established in the VAR (p = 1 in the VEC) to avoid losing an excessive number of degrees of freedom due to data limitations. In addition, we conduct unit root tests on all variables, and as shown in Table A2 of the appendix, all endogenous variables are non- stationary with integration order 1 (I (1)). Following Paiva (2006) and Arteaga et al. (2013), interest rate differentials variables are treated as exogenous as they are stationary (I (0)), and they are excluded from the cointegration vector. See Table A2 for the entire Unit Root Tests of all the variables in our VEC models.

Cointegration Tests

Once the VEC lags are defined, the cointegration test is applied using the trace test and the maximum eigenvalue test (eigen test) of Johansen (1992) for each resulting combination of one variable of each leading group, one variable for the exogenous Interest Rate Differentials group, and one constant. If at least one of the two tests concludes there is one cointegration relationship, the model is selected.

After the number of cointegration relationships for each combination of variables is established, we estimate all the VEC models with one cointegration relationship.

Model and Cointegration Vector Estimation

For the estimation of a VEC model, the following specification was used:

(1)

where

i is the subscript of the model, p is the order in which the variables are lagged in the VAR representation, α is a matrix of dimension K × r containing the convergence speeds to equilibrium, and [β; µ] is the matrix of dimension (K + 1) × r that represents the concatenation between the matrix β(K × r), which contains the long-term relationships and the array µ(1× r) that contains the constant term. Γ l (l = 1, . . . , p - 1) are matrices K× K containing the short-term fit coefficients, Z is the vector of exogenous variables that, in this case, are associated with the group of rate differentials, and ϵ is the 1 vector of errors.7

Real Equilibrium Exchange Rate and its Misalignment

The predicted value from the VEC model regression is interpreted as the ERER in the BEER literature. The ERER associated with each model is obtained from the models estimated in the previous section. The total equilibria are equivalent to the total number of possible models estimated. For the ERER calculation the linear combination in equation (2) between the vector (β +) and the observed data of each variable that composes it (X +) is performed. This estimate is done for each model i for each t

(2)

where β k,1 together with µ 1 are the coefficients of the first cointegration vector: β + associated with the model i. The equilibrium is noted by RERI to avoid confusion with the observed RERI.

Considering that RERI has been transformed into logarithms and that the cointegration vector is normalized, the logarithm of the equilibrium of the i-th model is obtained in each t:

(3)

Once the equilibrium has been calculated, the misalignment of model i is calculated for each time t as the percentage change between the observed exchange rate and the equilibrium rate.

Following the literature (Clark & MacDonald, 1998), a smoothed equilibrium measure is calculated. We use equation (3) but replace the right-hand side variables with the smoothed versions using the Hodrick and Prescott filter, denoted as x it . The aforementioned procedure is made to obtain the equilibrium that does not incorporate short-term movement of its fundamentals.

Then the smoothed misalignment is calculated as the percentage deviation between the observed exchange rate and the smoothed equilibrium rate.

Model Selection

After identifying all the misalignments, we filter out those models where 𝛽 1 + together with the exogenous component Φ do not meet the expected signs (as explained in Section II). The significance of the coefficients of the remaining models is evaluated, and the cases in which at least 4 out of 6 coefficients were significant (at 10% level) are selected. In addition to the sign and significance filter, all models that do not meet the criteria for non- autocorrelation, homoscedasticity, normality, and stationarity in the residuals are excluded.

Equilibrium and Misalignment Distribution

To obtain a central path of equilibrium and misalignment in each period of time, the selected models are grouped and their median is calculated for each t. This process is done for both smoothed and unsmoothed estimates. The equilibria are calculated for each time t, (t = 1, . . . , T ) and each model i, (i = 1, . . . , N ). The 20th and 80th percentiles are obtained in the same way and will represent the intervals around the central path (median). A matrix representation of this process is presented in Tables 2 and 3:

Table 2 Equilibrium Models 

Source: Own elaboration

Table 3 Distribution for each t 

Source: Author’s calculations.

Results

This section begins by showing the distribution of coefficients across all models8 to test the robustness of the sign and the magnitude of the estimated coefficients to alternative model specifications. The different hypotheses on the signs of the coefficients associated with the variables discussed in Section II are empirically addressed. Then, from the selection of models that meet the criteria on sign, significance and residual assumptions (as discussed in Section III), the empirical distribution of equilibria and misalignments are shown across all the range of models. It is important to note that we are addressing only one specific and narrow type of model uncertainty: combinations of contemporaneous variables of each type.

Distribution of Coefficients

In section B of the appendix (Figures A1 through A4), we report the distribution of the estimated coefficients associated with variables within the cointegration vector and across models. The proportion of red to white shows the share of estimations with statistically significant coefficients at the 10% level. These distributions illustrate the robustness of the sign and magnitude of the estimated coefficients to alternative model specifications. A negative (positive) coefficient implies that increases in the corresponding variable are associated with a real effective appreciation (depreciation) of the RER.

Our results suggest that the terms of trade group variables are robustly linked to real exchange rates in the sense that their coefficients among all six variables are, on average, significant in 79% of all possible models. Furthermore, in approximately 76% of the total models they have the theoretically predicted sign (Figure A1). The latter result strongly supports the theory that higher commodity terms of trade should lead to real exchange rate appreciation via real income effect (Neary, 1988; Ajevskis et al., 2014).

In the productivity group (Figure A2), the variables with the highest percentage of significant coefficients across all possible model combinations (and with the expected sign) are the ones relating productivity measures between Colombia and its main trading partners. Indeed, among the two variables measuring the relative productivity of Colombia and that of its main trading partners, 98% and 95% of the models were significant and met the expected sign, respectively. The worst-performing productivity proxy in this group is the per-capita relative index between the US and Colombia, of which 45.8% is significant and, among those, 53.5% have the expected positive sign. It is worth noting that as our variables are defined as ratios with Colombia in the denominator, the expected sign for the coefficients in this set of variables is positive. As mentioned in Section II, the inclusion of a productivity variable is commonly motivated by the Balassa- Samuelson theory. Our results largely support both the theoretical and empirical evidence that a rise in productivity implies a real appreciation of the local currency.

With respect to the Indebtedness group of variables, they consistently exhibit the expected sign in most variables, specifically the ones including outstanding debt (Figure A3). Public external debt outstanding as percentage of the moving sum four quarters of nominal GDP in USD, and NFA as percentage of nominal GDP, are statistically significant in over 95% of the regressions and, approximately, 92% exhibit the expected sign (positive for the public debt outstanding and negative for the NFA/GDP). Total external debt is another outperformer, with 77% of the coefficients being significant and 75% of the total estimated models exhibiting the expected positive sign. It is worth noting that NFA times the prime interest rate divided by the sum of four quarters of the GDP (NFA prime GDP), NFA times the prime real interest rate deflated by US CPI (NFA prime real) and NFA times the prime interest rate as percentage of real GDP (NFA prime REAL GDP) exhibit a distribution with 54%, 47% and 38% of the models, respectively, having the expected sign.

Lastly, in the fiscal group, all variables considered are significant in more than 52% of the cases (Figure A4). In particular, the three variables related to Public Consumption (Public Consumption, Public Consumption as a percentage of GDP, and Public Consumption as a share of Total Consumption) predominantly exhibit the expected negative sign. These results support the works of Maeso-Fernández et al. (2006) and Badia and Segura-Ubiergo (2014), which highlight the role of the composition of government spending as “increases in government spending-whether tax or debt-financed-will result in a real appreciation if skewed toward non-tradable goods.” Our results also seem to support the New-Keynesian approach, which posits that an increase in public spending generates an appreciation of the real exchange rate (negative sign), as it is primarily channeled towards non-tradable goods and services (De Gregorio & Wolf, 1994; De Gregorio et al., 1994; Froot & Rogoff, 1995). In the long term, high government/public sector spending, mainly if it is financed by debt, may widen the interest rate differential between the economy and the rest of the world as it increases the country’s risk premium (Bouakez & Eyquem, 2015; Kollmann, 2002; Schmitt-Grohé & Uribe, 2003; Senhadji, 2003). This may lead to distortions in the economy and undermine market confidence in a currency. Colombia’s persistent fiscal deficit could explain the positive coefficients on CNG Spending, NFPS Spending, and NFPS Spending as a percentage of GDP.

Distribution of ERER and Misalignment

As discussed in Section 5.1, both the magnitude and sign of the estimated coefficients are sensitive to the combinations of variables in a particular regression. Thus, the model implied that the ERER will also depend on the chosen specification and each model would imply a different path for the equilibrium exchange rate. For that reason, we present the empirical distributions of ERER and smoothed ERER (Ricci & MacDonald, 2003). In a VEC model, the equilibrium relationship results from multiplying the cointegration vector found by the values of the variables at each moment in time. In the smoothed ERER, we use the cointegration vector of the VEC and multiply it by the smoothed variables9 to omit transient movements in them that should not lead to changes in the ERER.

Figure 1 shows the empirical distribution of ERER (Panel A) and the empiri cal distribution of smoothed ERER (Panel B). The median of these empirical distributions shows that the country experienced a reduction in ERER from 2004 to 2013. In addition, the complete distribution also exhibits a trend towards appreciation of the ERER during these years. This result is associated with higher terms of trade,10 some improvements in relative productivity, an increase of government spending11 and a reduction of external indebtedness as a percentage of GDP.12 Arteaga et al. (2013) found a similar trend for ERER by estimating a VEC model for Colombia between 1994Q2 and 2012. Our estimation also reveals that from 2014 to 2019, ERER increased amidst a negative shock to the terms of trade, higher external debt and a deterioration of net foreign assets.13

Note: Figures in both Panel A and Panel B cover the period 2000Q1-2019Q4. Panel B reports the ERER distribution that results from replacing the fundamentals by its long-term equilibriums (Hodrick-Prescott trend component). The widest bands correspond to the area between percentiles 20 and 80 of the distribution. Source: own elaboration.

Figure 1 Distribution of ERER and smoothed ERER  

Figure 2 RER and smoothed RER misalignments  

Figure 2 also presents the corresponding misalignment of RER. According to both methodologies, during the global financial crisis (2008-2009) and the oil price shock (2014-2015), there was a significant deviation of the RER from the equilibrium during the sample period. Additionally, taking into account the flexible exchange rate regime adopted in Colombia since 2000, the RER oscillated around the equilibrium during our sample period.

Conclusions

The approach carried out in this work is framed within the Behavioral Equilibrium Exchange Rate (BEER), as defined by Clark and MacDonald (1998). Under this methodology, the equilibrium real exchange rate (ERER) is constructed based on reduced-form models and time series estimates that seek to capture how different variables determine the RER’s dynamics. According to this notion of equilibrium, the ERER varies over time and is specified as a function of its fundamentals, determined by macroeconomic theory. The literature (i.e., Adler & Grisse, 2017; Phillips et al., 2013) has identified that the estimation of the ERER through the BEER methodology tends to be extremely sensitive to the model specification and the set of fundamentals used. In general, BEER models suggest several variables as potential drivers of real exchange rates. This gives rise to the issue of model uncertainty, as coefficients and equilibrium rates depend on the particular specification being estimated. To address this issue, we establish five groups of multiple fundamentals that, according to the literature, best explain ERER movements: Indebtedness, Fiscal aggregates, Productivity, Terms-of-Trade, and Interest Rate Differentials. We use several proxies for each group and estimate real exchange rate VEC models for all possible combinations of the fundamental variables across groups (fixing one variable for each group of fundamentals). From a set of filtered models, we derive an empirical distribution of ERER that allows us to determine with greater certainty, among hundreds of plausible economic specifications, whether the real exchange rate is in equilibrium or misaligned. It is important to note that we address only one specific and narrow type of model uncertainty: combinations of contemporaneous variables of each type. To address other uncertainty sources, future works

should also consider robustness among different methodological specifications, such as Autoregressive Distributed Lag Model (ARDL), Fully Modified OLS (FMOLS), or Dynamic OLS (DOLS), among others.

The median of the empirical distributions shows that from 2004 to 2013, Colombia experienced a reduction in ERER and a trend towards its appreciation. This result is associated with higher terms of trade, a slight improvement in relative productivity, an increase in government spending and a reduction in external indebtedness as a share of GDP. Our estimations also reveal that between 2014 and 2019, ERER depreciated as a consequence of a negative terms-of-trade shock, higher external debt and the deterioration of net foreign assets.

Acknowledgements

The authors give special thanks to Marcela Torres, Juliana María Huertas and Juan Felipe Salamanca for their outstanding support as research assistants. Also, to Norberto Rodríguez, Daniel Parra, Carlos Huertas, Hernando Vargas, Juan José Ospina, Joan Camilo Granados, Nicolás Martínez, Juan Pablo Cote and Jair Ojeda for their invaluable insights, commentaries and econometric support.

The opinions, statements, findings, and interpretations contained in this document are the sole responsibility of the authors and do not represent the position of Banco de la República or its Board of Directors. All errors and omissions in this work are our responsibility.

A version of this paper was published on December 20, 2022, on Banco de la República working paper series “Borradores de Economía”: Salazar- Díaz, A., A. L. Garavito-Acosta, S. Restrepo-Ángel, and L.V. Arcila-Agudelo (2022). Real Equilibrium Exchange Rate in Colombia: Thousands of VECMS Approach. Borradores de Economía 1221.

References

Adler, K., & Grisse, C. (2017). Thousands of Beers: Take Your Pick. Review of International Economics, 25(5), 1078-1104. https://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12296Links ]

Ajevskis, V., Rimgailaite, R., Rutkaste, U., & Tkacevs, O. (2014). The Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate: Pros and Cons of Different Approaches with Application to Latvia. Baltic Journal of Economics, 14(1-2), 101- 123. https://doi.org/10.1080/1406099X.2014.993853Links ]

Alonso, G., Hernández, J. N., Pulido, J. D., & Villa, M. (2008). Medidas alternativas de tasa de cambio real para Colombia [Borradores de Economía 514]. Banco de la República. https://www.banrep.gov.co/es/medidas-alternativas-tasa-cambio-real-para-colombiaLinks ]

Arteaga, C., Granados, J., & Joya, J. O. (2013). El comportamiento del tipo de cambio real en Colombia: ¿explicado por sus fundamentales? Ensayos sobre Política Económica 31(72), 1-17. https://doi.org/10.32468/Espe.7201Links ]

Backus, D. K., Kehoe, P. J., & Kydland, F. E. (1995). International Business Cycles: Theory and Evidence. In T. F. Cooley (ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research (331-356). Princeton University Press. https://doi.org/10.21034/qr.1742Links ]

Badia, M. M., & Segura-Ubiergo, M. A. (2014). Real Exchange Rate Appreciation in Emerging Markets: Can Fiscal Policy Help? [IMF Working Papers No. 2014/001]. International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/31/Real-Exchange-Rate-Appreciation-in-Emerging-Markets-Can-Fiscal-Policy-Help-41196Links ]

Balassa, B. (1964). The Purchasing-Power Parity Doctrine: A Reappraisal. Journal of Political Economy, 72(6), 584-596. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1829464Links ]

Banco de la República (n.d.). Metodología de cálculo de los índices de precios de exportaciones, importaciones y términos de intercambio según los índices de precios del productor (IPP) [methodologic note]. Accessed on October 10 2022. https://www.banrep.gov.co/sites/default/files/paginas/Nota_metodologica_terminos_intercambio_IPP.pdfLinks ]

Bénassy-Quéré, A., Béreau, S., & Mignon, V. (2009a). Robust Estimations of Equilibrium Exchange Rates Within the G20: A Panel Beer Approach. Scottish Journal of Political Economy , 56 (5), 608-633. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9485.2009.00500.xLinks ]

Bénassy-Quéré, A., Béreau, S., & Mignon, V. (2009b). Taux de change d’équilibre. Revue Èconomique, 60(3), 657-666. https://www.cairn.info/revue-economique-2009-3-page-657.htmLinks ]

Bouakez, H., & Eyquem, A. (2015). Government Spending, Monetary Policy, and the Real Exchange Rate. Journal of International Money and Finance, 56 (1), 178-201. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2014.09.010Links ]

Bussiére, M., Cazorzi, M., Chudík, A., & Dieppe, A. (2010). Methodological Advances in the Assessment of Currency Misalignments [ECB working paper No.1151]. European Central Bank. https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp1151.pdfLinks ]

Calderón, C. (2004). Un análisis del comportamiento del tipo de cambio real en Chile [working paper No. 266]. Banco Central de Chile. https://www.bcentral.cl/nota-de-prensa-detalle/-/asset_publisher/L832eVmsZG9c/content/un-analisis-del-comportamiento-del-tipo-de-cambi o-real-en-chile-4Links ]

Caputo, R. (2015). Persistent real misalignments and the role of the exchange rate regime. Economics Letters 135, 112-116. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2015.08.011Links ]

Caputo, R., & Núñez, M. (2008). Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate in Chile: Alternative Approaches. Economía Chilena, 11(2), 59-77. https://xn-economachilena-5lb.cl/index.php/economiachilena/article/view/110Links ]

Clark, P. B., & MacDonald, R. (1998). Exchange Rates and Economic Fundamentals: A Methodological Comparison of Beers and Feers [IMF Working Papers No. 1998/067]. https://www.imf.org/en/Publication s/WP/Issues/2016/12/30/Exchange-Rates-and-Economic-Fundament als-A-Methodological-Comparison-of-BEERs-and-FEERs-2592Links ]

Clark, P. B., & MacDonald, R. (2004). Filtering the Beer: A Permanent and Transitory Decomposition. Global Finance Journal, 15(1), 29-56. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gfj.2003.10.005Links ]

Cosset, J.-C., & Roy, J. (1991). The Determinants of Country Risk Ratings. Journal of International Business Studies, 22, 135-142. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8490296Links ]

De Broeck, M., & Slok, T. (2006). Interpreting Real Exchange Rate Movements in Transition Countries. Journal of International Economics, 68, 368-383. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.05.012Links ]

De Grauwe, P., & Mongelli, F. (2005). Endogeneities of Optimum Currency Areas: What Brings Countries Sharing a Single Currency Closer Together? [ working paper series No. 468]. European Central Bank. https://ideas.repec.org/p/ecb/ecbwps/2005468.htmlLinks ]

De Gregorio, J., & Wolf, H. (1994). Terms of Trade, Productivity, and The Real Exchange Rate [NBER Working Paper No. 4807]. National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w4807Links ]

De Gregorio, J., Giovannini, A., & Wolf, H. (1994). International Evidence on Tradables and Nontradables Inflation. European Economic Review, 38 (6), 1225-1244. https://doi.org/10.1016/0014-2921(94)90070-1Links ]

Echavarría, J. J., Vásquez, D., & Villamizar-Villegas, M. (2005). La tasa de cambio real en Colombia: ¿muy lejos del equilibrio? Ensayos Sobre Política Económica, 23 (49), 134-191. https://doi.org/10.32468/Espe.4904Links ]

Echavarría, J. J., Enciso, E. L., & Misas, M. (2007). La tasa de cambio real de equilibrio en Colombia y su desalineamiento: estimación a través de un modelo SVEC [Borradores de Economía No. 472]. Banco de la República. https://www.banrep.gov.co/es/tasa-cambio-real-equilibrio-colombia-y-su-desalineamiento-estimacion-traves-modelo-svec [ Links ]

Edwards, S. (1989). Exchange Rate Misalignment in Developing countries. The World Bank Research Observer, 4 (1), 3-21. https://doi.org/10.1093/wbro/4.1.3Links ]

Fidora, M., Giordano, C., & Schmitz, M. (2021). Real Exchange Rate Misalignments in the Euro Area. Open Economies Review, 32(1), 71-107. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-020-09596-1Links ]

Fischer, C. (2004). Real Currency Appreciation in Accession Countries: Balassa-Samuelson and Investment Demand. Review of World Economics, 140(2), 179-210. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02663645Links ]

Fleming, J. M. (1962). Domestic Financial Policies under Fixed and Floating Exchange Rates. IMF Staff Papers, 9(3), 369-379. https://www.elibrary.imf.org/view/journals/024/1962/003/article-A004-en.xmlLinks ]

Froot, K. A., & Rogoff, K. (1995). Perspectives on PPP and Long-Run Real Exchange Rates. Handbook of International Economics(3), 1647-1688. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4404(05)80012-7Links ]

Galstyan, V., & Lane, P. R. (2009). The Composition of Government Spending and the Real Exchange Rate. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41(6), 1233-1249. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4616.2009.00254.xLinks ]

Garavito, A., López, D. C., & Montes E. (2011). Aproximación a los índices de valor unitario y quantum del comercio exterior colombiano [Borradores de Economía, 680]. Banco de la República. https://www.banrep.gov.co/es/node/25550Links ]

Harberger, A. C. (2004). The Real Exchange Rate: Issues of Concept and Measurement. University of California. https://www.imf.org/external/np/res/seminars/2004/mussa/pdf/haberg.pdfLinks ]

Isard, P. (2007). Equilibrium Exchange Rates: Assessment Methodologies [ IMF Working Paper No. 2007/296]. International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/31/Equilibrium-Exchange-Rates-Assessment-Methodologies-21517Links ]

Johansen, S. (1992). Cointegration in Partial Systems and the Efficiency of Single-Equation Analysis. Journal of Econometrics, 52(3), 389-402. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(92)90019-NLinks ]

Kollmann, R. (2002). Monetary Policy Rules in the Open Economy: Effects on Welfare and Business Cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49(5), 989-1015. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00132-0Links ]

Kollmann, R. (2010). Government Purchases and the Real Exchange Rate. Open Economies Review , 21(1), 49-64. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-009-9148-2Links ]

Lee, M. J., Ostry, M. J. D., Prati, M. A., Antonio, R. M. L., & Milesi-Ferretti, M. G. (2008). Foundations of International Macroeconomics. International Monetary Fund. [ Links ]

Maeso-Fernández, F., Osbat, C., & Schnatz, B. (2002). Determinants of the Euro Real Effective Exchange Rate: A Beer/Peer Approach. Australian Economic Papers, 41(5), 437-461. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8454.00174Links ]

Maeso-Fernández, F., Osbat, C., & Schnatz, B. (2006). Towards the Estimation of Equilibrium Exchange Rates for Transition Economies: Method ological Issues and a Panel Cointegration Perspective. Journal of Comparative Economics, 34(3), 499-517. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2006.05.003Links ]

Mano, R. (2019). The Level REER Model in the External Balance Assessment (EBA) Methodology [ IMF Working Paper No. 2019/192]. International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/20 19/09/13/The-Level-REER-model-in-the-External-Balance-Assessment-EBA-Methodology-48588Links ]

Mundell, R. A. (1963). Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 29(5), 475-485. https://doi.org/10.2307/139336Links ]

Neary, P. (1988). Determinants of the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate. The American Economic Review, 78(1), 210-215. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1814708Links ]

Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (1996). Foundations of International Macroeconomics . MIT press. [ Links ]

Oliveros, H., & Huertas-Campos, C. A. (2003). Desequilibrios nominales y reales del tipo de cambio en Colombia. Ensayos Sobre Política Económica , 21 (43), 32-65. https://doi.org/10.32468/Espe.4302Links ]

Paiva, C. (2006). External Adjustment and Equilibrium Exchange rate in Brazil [ IMF Working Paper s No. 2006/221]. International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/31/Externa l-Adjustment-and-Equilibrium-Exchange-Rate-in-Brazil-19869Links ]

Phillips, S., Catão, L., Ricci, L. A., Bems, R., Das, M., Di Giovanni, J., & Unsal, F. (2013). The External Balance Assessment (Eba) Methodology. International Monetary Fund. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781484346686.001Links ]

Puyana-Martínez, R. (2010). El efecto Balassa-Samuelson en Colombia [ Borradores de Economía No. 630]. https://doi.org/10.32468/be.630Links ]

Ravn, M. O., Schmitt-Grohe, S., & Uribe, M. (2007). Pricing to Habits and the Law of One Price. American Economic Review, 92(2), 232-238. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.97.2.232Links ]

Ricci, L. A., & MacDonald, R. (2003). Estimation of the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate for South Africa [ IMF Working Paper Series No. 2003/044]. International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/30/Estimation-of-the-Equilibrium-R eal-Exchange-Rate-for-South-Africa-16340Links ]

Saxegaard, M., Roudet, S., & Tsangarides, C. (2007). Estimation of Equilibrium Exchange Rates in the WAEMU: A Robustness Analysis [ IMF Working Paper Series No. 2007/194]. International Monetary Fund . https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/31/Estimation-of-Equilibrium-Exchange-Rates-in-the-WAEMU-A-Robustness-Analysis-21194Links ]

Rubaszek, M., & Rawdanowicz, L. (2009). Economic Convergence and The Fundamental Equilibrium Exchange rate in Central and Eastern Europe. International Review of Financial Analysis, 18(5), 277-284. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2009.09.006Links ]

Samuelson, P. A. (1964). Theoretical Notes on Trade Problems. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 46 (2), 145-154. https://doi.org/10.2307/1928178 Links ]

Sarno, L., & Taylor, M. (2003). The Economics of Exchange Rates. Cambridge University Press. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2728909Links ]

Schmitt-Grohé, S., & Uribe, M. (2003). Closing Small Open Economy Models. Journal of International Economics , 61(1), 163-185. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/S0022-1996)0200056-9Links ]

Senhadji, A. S. (2003). External Shocks and Debt Accumulation in A Small Open Economy. Review of Economic Dynamics, 6 (1), 207-239. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1094-2025(02)00015-7Links ]

Stein, J. (1990). The Real Exchange Rate. Journal of Banking and Finance, 14(5), 1045-78. https://doi.org/10.1016/0378-4266(90)90026-XLinks ]

1See Phillips et al. (2013) for a description of the methodology used in the IMF’s external balance assessments.

2Our entire dataset consists of 35 variables. More detailed information about the dataset can be found on Section II.

3We used the specification for the real exchange rate given by the multilateral RER index weighted by total non-traditional goods trade, deflated by the consumer price index.

4This methodology seeks to decompose the estimated BEER into transitory and permanent components, making the PEERs smoother than the BEERs.

5The non-traditional weights correspond to the 12th moving average of the share in total trade of the 22 main trading partners for Colombia (imports and exports excluding coffee, oil, coal, ferronickel, emeralds and gold).

6The main reason for this is computational since having more than one cointegration relationship is required to estimate more than one equilibrium for the same model (one for each cointegration relationship). The second reason is that forcing to estimate a single cointegration vector when the test suggests more than one may be wrong. If it is being suggested that there is more than one, there may be different signs and significance levels.

7As our aim is not to make forecasts and/or impulse-response analysis, the order in which the variables enter the cointegration equation does not matter.

8Previous to eliminating those with a different expected sign, not significant, nor those of models whose residuals do not meet the desired assumptions.

9Resulting from substituting the fundamentals by its Hodrick-Prescott trend component to obtain the equilibrium.

10Between 2004 and 2013, terms of trade increased by 45% due to the price commodity boom, including higher oil prices, which have had a significant share in Colombian exports. There was a transitory decline in terms of trade explained by the oil prices reduction in the first years after the beginning of the global financial crisis (2008).

11According to the Fiscal Monitor of the International Monetary Fund, total government spending expanded from 26.6% of GDP in 2004 to 30% of GDP in 2013.

12Total external debt dropped from 40.6% of GDP in 2003 to 24.1% of GDP in 2013.

13During this period, Colombia raised its external debt as a share of GDP (from 24% in 2013 to 43% in 2019), which in turn greatly deteriorated the net foreign position as a share of GDP (from -25.3% in 2013 to -48.9% in 2019).

Cómo citar / How to cite this item: Salazar-Díaz, A., Garavito-Acosta, A. L., Restrepo-Ángel, S., & Arcila-Agudelo, L. V. (2023). Real Equilibrium Exchange Rate in Colombia: Thousands of VEC Models Approach. Lecturas de Economía, 99, 33-78. https://doi.org/10.17533/udea.le.n99a352279

Appendix

Table A1 ERER Determinants According to Literature 

Source: Own elaboration.

Table A2 Unit Root Test 

ADF order PP order
Panel A. Non-stationary variables
RERI CPI NT I(1)*** I(1)***
Public consumption I(1)*** I(1)***
Public comsumption % Total Consumption I(1)** I(1)**
CNG Spending I(1)*** I(1)***
CNG Outstanding Debt I(1)*** I(1)**
NFPS Spending I(1)*** I(1)***
Public consumption % GDP I(1)*** I(1)***
NFPS Spending % GDP a/ I(1)* I(1)***
Relative Labour Productivity USA/COL I(1)*** I(1)***
T/NT relative GDP USA/COL I(1)*** I(1)***
Trade partners/COL index ratio I(1)*** I(1)***
Per capita trade partners/COL index ratio I(1)*** I(1)***
Per capita relative index USA/COL I(1)*** I(1)***
GDP PPP Per capita ratio USA/COL I(1)*** I(1)***
Relative labour productivity USA/COL I(1)*** I(1)***
T/NT relative GDP USA/COL I(1)*** I(1)***
Public external debt outstanding I(1)*** I(1)***
Total external debt I(1)*** I(1)***
NFA prime REAL GDP a/ I(1)*** I(1)***
NFA GDP I(1)*** I(1)***
Real NFA I(1)*** I(1)***
NFA prime GDP I(1)*** I(1)***
Private external debt a/ I(1)*** I(1)***
NFA prime real a/ I(1)*** I(1)***
Terms of Trade CE I(1)*** I(1)***
Terms of Trade PPI I(1)*** I(1)***
Mining Terms of Trade I(1)*** I(1)***
Implicit Real Oil Price I(1)*** I(1)***
Real Brent price I(1)*** I(1)***
ADF order PP order
National accounts Terms of Trade I(1)*** I(1)***
Panel B. Non-stationary Variables
Dif Assets-Prime I(0)*** I(0)***
Diff FTD 90 days I(0)*** I(0)***
Diff FTD360-Prime I(0)*** I(0)***
Diff FTD-Prime I(0)*** I(0)***
Diff FTD-3mlibor I(0)*** I(0)***

Note: Unit root tests were performed under a type of model with constant.

Unit root test under a type of model without constant nor tendency. Significance level: ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Source: Own elaboration.

Non-Traditional Real Exchange Rate Index Deflated by CPI

The most common application of the RER is carried out with the consumer price index (CPI). This indicator aggregates both tradable and non- tradable goods and has several advantages since it is highly available in countries and frequency (Harberger, 2004). Its formula is defined as follows:

where i = 1, . . . , 22 is the number of trading partners used. NERI i corresponds to the nominal exchange rate index for each trading partner (average 2010 = 100). The weights (ω i ) for calculating the multilateral rate is given by total trade with each country (exports plus imports) so that the main trading partners are given greater importance. The formula that describes the weights is the following:

Where 𝑋 𝐶𝑜𝑙 𝑖 are Colombia’s exports to country i and 𝑀 𝐶𝑜𝑙 𝑖 are Colombia’s imports from country i. The dynamics of the 𝑅??𝑅𝐼 1 indicator are interpreted as changes in the competitiveness of the country, so that if the 𝑅𝐸𝑅𝐼 1 appreciates, it is interpreted as a loss in Colombia’s international competitiveness.

Distribution of Coefficients

Figures AD.1 through AD.4 plot the distribution of coefficients across all the models in which they appear. The proportion of red to white illustrates the share of estimations in which the coefficient is statistically significant at the 10% level (“% Significant”). “% Expected Sign” corresponds to the proportion of models that meet the expected sign over the total number of models. White bars correspond to non-significant coefficients and red bars to significant coefficients.

Table A3 Description of Variables 

Variable name Description Source
RERI CPI NT Real exchange rate index (Details in An- Banrep
nex C)
Diff Assets Prime Difference between Colombian real in- Banrep-FRED Economic Data
terest rate and Fed’s real prime interest
rate.
Diff FTD 90 days Difference of 90-day real fixed-term Banrep-FRED Economic Data
certificate of deposit (CD) rates be-
tween Colombia and the US
Relative Labour Pro- Relative labour productiv- DANE-FRED Economic Data
ductivity USA COL ity USA/COL (industry sec-
tor/manufacturing sector)
Terms of Trade CEa Terms of Trade index (2010 = 100) ac- Banrep
cording to trade methodology
Terms of Trade PPI b Terms-of-Trade according to the pro- Banrep
ducer price index (PPI) methodology
index (2010=100)
Mining Terms of Trade Mining sector Terms-of-Trade index Banrep
(2010=100)
Public consumption Public consumption (moving average DANE
four quarters)
Public comsumption % Public consumption as percentage of DANE
Total Consumption total consumption (moving average
four quarters)
CNG Spending Central National Government (CNG) MinHacienda
Spending (moving average four quar-
ters)
CNG Outstanding CNG Outstanding Debt (moving MinHacienda.
Debt aveage four quarters)
NFPS Spending Non-Financial Public Sector (NFPS) MinHacienda.
spending (moving average four quar-
ters)
TNT relative GDP US Tradables/Non-tradables relative GDP DANE-BEA
COL of US vs. COL Tradables/Non-
tradables relative GDP of US vs. COL
Diff FTD360 Prime Difference of 360- day real fixed Banrep-FRED Economic Data
term certificate of deposit (CD) rates
between Colombia and the US (Diff
FTD360-Prime)
Diff FTD Prime Difference between real Fixed-term De- Banrep-FRED Economic Data
posit (FTD) interest rate and the real
prime interest rate (Diff FTD-Prime)
Diff FTD 3mlibor Difference between real Fixed-term De- Banrep-FRED Economic Data
posit (FTD) interest rate and the 3-
month real libor interest rate (Diff
FTD-3mlibor)
Public external debt Public external debt outstanding as Banrep
outstanding percentage of nominal GDP in USD
(moving sum four quarters)
Total external debt Total external debt outstanding as per- Banrep
centage of nominal GDP in USD
(moving sum four quarters)
Trade partners COL in- Trade partners/COL index ratio (Ra- DANE-IMF
dex ratio tio between the quarterly GDP PPP in-
dex of the trading partners, weighted
by trade, and the PPP GDP index of
COL)
Per capita trade part- Per capita trade partners/COL index ra- DANE-IMF
ners COL index ratio tio (Ratio between the quarterly GDP
per capita in PPP of the trading part-
ners, weighted by trade, and the index
of the GDP per capita in PPP of COL)
Implicit Real Oil Price Implicit Real Oil price (deflated by US FRED Economic Data
CPI)
Real Brent price Real Brent price (deflated by US CPI) FRED Economic Data
NFA prime REAL NFA times prime interest rate as per- Banrep-FRED Economic Data
GDP centage of real GDP (all deflated by US
CPI)
NFA GDP NFA as percentage of nominal GDP in Banrep-FRED Economic Data
USD (moving sum four quarters)
Real NFA NFA deflated by US CPI Banrep-FRED Economic Data
NFA prime GDP NFA times the prime interest rate di- Banrep-FRED Economic Data
vided by total GDP (sum four quarters)
National accounts Terms-of-Trade using implicit deflator DANE
Terms of Trade by Colombian National Accounts
Private external debt Private external debt outstanding as Banrep
percentage of nominal GDP in USD
(moving sum four quarters)
Per capita relative index Per capita relative index USA/COL DANE-FRED Economic Data
USA COL (Ratio between the quarterly GDP per
capita of the US and the index of the
GDP per capita of COL)
GP PPP Per capita ratio GDP PPP Per capita ratio USA/COL DANE-IMF
USA COL (Ratio between the quarterly GDP per
capita in PPP of the US and the index
of the GDP
per capita in PPP of COL) DANE-IMF
NFA prime real NFA times the prime interest rate de- Banrep-FRED Economic Data
flated by US CPI
Public consumption % Public consumption as percentage of DANE
GDP GDP (moving average four quarters)
NFPS Spending % Non-Financial Public Sector (NFPS) MinHacienda.
GDP spending as percentage of total GDP
(moving average four quarters)
Relative labour prod Relative labour productivity DANE-FRED Economic Data
USA COL MA 4q USA/COL (industry sector/ man-
ufacturing sector) (moving average
four quarters)
TNT relative GDP US Tradables/ Non-tradables relative GDP DANE-FRED Economic Data
COL MA 4q of US vs. COL, Tradables/ Non-
tradables relative GDP of US vs. COL
(moving average four quarters)

Notes: a/ For more details on the methodology see Garavito et al. (2011).

b/ It is calculated as the quotient between the price index of exported goods and the price index of imported goods. These indices are obtained by adding the price indices of different economic activities, according to ISIC Rev.4 at two digits, weighted by foreign trade figures. For more details, check the calculation methodology at Banco de la República (n.d.).

Source: DIAN-DANE customs statistics.

Source: Own elaboration.

Figure A1 Distribution of coefficients - Terms-of-Trade group  

Source: Own elaboration.

Figure A2 Distribution of coefficients - Productivity group  

Source: Own elaboration.

Figure A3 Distribution of coefficients - Indebtedness  

Source: Own elaboration.

Figure A4 Distribution of coefficients - Fiscal Group  

Recibido: 31 de Diciembre de 2022; Aprobado: 16 de Marzo de 2023

Creative Commons License Este es un artículo publicado en acceso abierto bajo una licencia Creative Commons